Interest rate

An interest rate is the rate at which interest is paid by a borrower for the use of money that they borrow from a lender. For example, a small company borrows capital from a bank to buy new assets for their business, and in return the lender receives interest at a predetermined interest rate for deferring the use of funds and instead lending it to the borrower. Interest rates are normally expressed as a percentage of the principal for a period of one year[1].

Interest rates targets are also a vital tool of monetary policy and are taken into account when dealing with variables like investment, inflation, and unemployment.

Contents

Historical interest rates

In the past two centuries, interest rates have been variously set either by national governments or central banks. For example, the Federal Reserve federal funds rate in the United States has varied between about 0.25% to 19% from 1954 to 2008, while the Bank of England base rate varied between 0.5% and 15% from 1989 to 2009,[2][3] and Germany experienced rates close to 90% in the 1920s down to about 2% in the 2000s.[4][5] During an attempt to tackle spiraling hyperinflation in 2007, the Central Bank of Zimbabwe increased interest rates for borrowing to 800%.[6]

The interest rates on prime credits in the late 1970s and early 1980s were far higher than had been recorded – higher than previous US peaks since 1800, than British peaks since 1700, or than Dutch peaks since 1600; "since modern capital markets came into existence, there have never been such high long-term rates" as in this period.[7]

Interest Rates in the United States

In the United States, authority for interest rate decisions is divided between the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve (Board) and the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). The Board decides on changes in discount rates after recommendations submitted by one or more of the regional Federal Reserve Banks. The FOMC decides on open market operations, including the desired levels of central bank money or the desired federal funds market rate.

Reasons for interest rate change

Real vs nominal interest rates

The nominal interest rate is the amount, in money terms, of interest payable.

For example, suppose a household deposits $100 with a bank for 1 year and they receive interest of $10. At the end of the year their balance is $110. In this case, the nominal interest rate is 10% per annum.

The real interest rate, which measures the purchasing power of interest receipts, is calculated by adjusting the nominal rate charged to take inflation into account. (See real vs. nominal in economics.)

If inflation in the economy has been 10% in the year, then the $110 in the account at the end of the year buys the same amount as the $100 did a year ago. The real interest rate, in this case, is zero.

After the fact, the 'realized' real interest rate, which has actually occurred, is given by the Fisher equation, and is

r = \frac{1%2Bi}{1%2Bp}-1\,\!

where p = the actual inflation rate over the year. The linear approximation

r \approx i-p\,\!

is widely used.

The expected real returns on an investment, before it is made, are:

i_r = i_n - p_e\,\!

where:

i_r\,\! = real interest rate
i_n\,\! = nominal interest rate
p_e\,\! = expected or projected inflation over the year

Market interest rates

There is a market for investments which ultimately includes the money market, bond market, stock market and currency market as well as retail financial institutions like banks.

Exactly how these markets function is a complex question. However, economists generally agree that the interest rates yielded by any investment take into account:

This rate incorporates the deferred consumption and alternative investments elements of interest.

Inflationary expectations

According to the theory of rational expectations, people form an expectation of what will happen to inflation in the future. They then ensure that they offer or ask a nominal interest rate that means they have the appropriate real interest rate on their investment.

This is given by the formula:

i_n = i_r %2B p_e\,\!

where:

i_n\,\! = offered nominal interest rate
i_r\,\! = desired real interest rate
p_e\,\! = inflationary expectations

Risk

The level of risk in investments is taken into consideration. This is why very volatile investments like shares and junk bonds have higher returns than safer ones like government bonds.

The extra interest charged on a risky investment is the risk premium. The required risk premium is dependent on the risk preferences of the lender.

If an investment is 50% likely to go bankrupt, a risk-neutral lender will require their returns to double. So for an investment normally returning $100 they would require $200 back. A risk-averse lender would require more than $200 back and a risk-loving lender less than $200. Evidence suggests that most lenders are in fact risk-averse.

Generally speaking a longer-term investment carries a maturity risk premium, because long-term loans are exposed to more risk of default during their duration.

Liquidity preference

Most investors prefer their money to be in cash than in less fungible investments. Cash is on hand to be spent immediately if the need arises, but some investments require time or effort to transfer into spendable form. This is known as liquidity preference. A 1-year loan, for instance, is very liquid compared to a 10-year loan. A 10-year US Treasury bond, however, is liquid because it can easily be sold on the market.

A market interest-rate model

A basic interest rate pricing model for an asset

i_n = i_r %2B p_e %2B rp %2B lp\,\!

Assuming perfect information, pe is the same for all participants in the market, and this is identical to:

i_n = i^*_n %2B rp %2B lp\,\!

where

in is the nominal interest rate on a given investment
ir is the risk-free return to capital
i*n = the nominal interest rate on a short-term risk-free liquid bond (such as U.S. Treasury Bills).
rp = a risk premium reflecting the length of the investment and the likelihood the borrower will default
lp = liquidity premium (reflecting the perceived difficulty of converting the asset into money and thus into goods).

Interest rate notations

What is commonly referred to as the interest rate in the media is generally the rate offered on overnight deposits by the Central Bank or other authority, annualized.

The total interest on an investment depends on the timescale the interest is calculated on, because interest paid may be compounded.

In finance, the effective interest rate is often derived from the yield, a composite measure which takes into account all payments of interest and capital from the investment.

In retail finance, the annual percentage rate and effective annual rate concepts have been introduced to help consumers easily compare different products with different payment structures.

Interest rates in macroeconomics

Elasticity of substitution

The elasticity of substitution (full name should be the marginal rate of substitution of the relative allocation) affects the real interest rate. The larger the magnitude of the elasticity of substitution, the more the exchange, and the lower the real interest rate.

Output and unemployment

Interest rates are the main determinant of investment on a macroeconomic scale. The current thought is that if interest rates increase across the board, then investment decreases, causing a fall in national income. However, the Austrian School of Economics sees higher rates as leading to greater investment in order to earn the interest to pay the depositors. Higher rates encourage more saving and thus more investment and thus more jobs to increase production to increase profits. Higher rates also discourage economically unproductive lending such as consumer credit and mortgage lending. Also consumer credit tends to be used by consumers to buy imported products whereas business loans tend to be domestic and lead to more domestic job creation [and/or capital investment in machinery] in order to increase production to earn more profit.

A government institution, usually a central bank, can lend money to financial institutions to influence their interest rates as the main tool of monetary policy. Usually central bank interest rates are lower than commercial interest rates since banks borrow money from the central bank then lend the money at a higher rate to generate most of their profit.

By altering interest rates, the government institution is able to affect the interest rates faced by everyone who wants to borrow money for economic investment. Investment can change rapidly in response to changes in interest rates and the total output.

Open Market Operations in the United States

The Federal Reserve (often referred to as 'The Fed') implements monetary policy largely by targeting the federal funds rate. This is the rate that banks charge each other for overnight loans of federal funds, which are the reserves held by banks at the Fed. Open market operations are one tool within monetary policy implemented by the Federal Reserve to steer short-term interest rates. Using the power to buy and sell treasury securities.

Money and inflation

Loans, bonds, and shares have some of the characteristics of money and are included in the broad money supply.

By setting i*n, the government institution can affect the markets to alter the total of loans, bonds and shares issued. Generally speaking, a higher real interest rate reduces the broad money supply.

Through the quantity theory of money, increases in the money supply lead to inflation.

Mathematical note

Because interest and inflation are generally given as percentage increases, the formulae above are (linear) approximations.

For instance,

i_n = i_r %2B p_e\,\!

is only approximate. In reality, the relationship is

(1 %2B i_n) = (1 %2B i_r)(1 %2B p_e)\,\!

so

i_r = \frac {1 %2B i_n} {1 %2B p_e} - 1\,\!

The two approximations, eliminating higher order terms, are:

\begin{align}
(1%2Bx)(1%2By) &= 1%2Bx%2By%2Bxy &&\approx 1%2Bx%2By\\
\frac{1}{1%2Bx} &= 1-x%2Bx^2-x^3%2B\cdots &&\approx 1-x
\end{align}

The formulae in this article are exact if logarithms of indices are used in place of rates.

Negative interest rates

Nominal interest rates are normally positive, but not always. Given the alternative of holding cash, and thus earning 0%, rather than lending it out, profit-seeking lenders will not lend below 0%, as that will guarantee a loss, and a bank offering a negative deposit rate will find few takers, as savers will instead hold cash.[8]

However, central bank rates can, in fact, be negative; in July 2009 Sweden's Riksbank was the first central bank to use negative interest rates, lowering its deposit rate to –0.25%, a policy advocated by deputy governor Lars E. O. Svensson.[9] This negative interest rate is possible because Swedish banks, as regulated companies, must hold these reserves with the central bank—they do not have the option of holding cash.

More often, real interest rates can be negative, when nominal interest rates are below inflation. When this is done via government policy (for example, via reserve requirements), this is deemed financial repression, and was practiced by countries such as the United States and United Kingdom following World War II (from 1945) until the late 1970s or early 1980s (during and following the Post–World War II economic expansion).[10][11] In the late 1970s, United States Treasury securities with negative real interest rates were deemed certificates of confiscation.[12]

Negative interest rates have been proposed in the past, notably in the late 19th century by Silvio Gesell.[13] A negative interest rate can be described (as by Gesell) as a "tax on holding money"; he proposed it as the Freigeld (free money) component of his Freiwirtschaft (free economy) system. To prevent people from holding cash (and thus earning 0%), Gesell suggested issuing money for a limited duration, after which it must be exchanged for new bills—attempts to hold money thus result in it expiring and becoming worthless. Along similar lines, John Maynard Keynes approving cited the idea of a carrying tax on money,[13] (1936, The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money) but dismissed it due to administrative difficulties.[14] More recently, a carry tax on currency was proposed by a Federal Reserve employee (Marvin Goodfriend) in 1999, to be implemented via magnetic strips on bills, deducting the carry tax upon deposit, with the tax based on how the bill had been held.[14]

It has been proposed that a negative interest rate can in principle be levied on existing paper currency via a serial number lottery: choosing a random number 0 to 9 and declaring that bills whose serial number end in that digit are worthless would yield a negative 10% interest rate, for instance (choosing the last two digits would allow a negative 1% interest rate, and so forth). This was proposed by an anonymous student of N. Gregory Mankiw,[13] though more as a thought experiment than a genuine proposal.[15]

See also

Notes

  1. ^ Definition of interest rate from Investorwords.com
  2. ^ moneyextra.com Interest Rate History. Retrieved 2008-10-27
  3. ^ news.bbc.co.uk UK interest rates lowered to 0.5%
  4. ^ (Homer, Sylla & Sylla 1996, p. 509)
  5. ^ Bundesbank. BBK - Statistics - Time series database. Retrieved 2008-10-27
  6. ^ worldeconomies.co.uk Zimbabwe currency revised to help inflation
  7. ^ (Homer, Sylla & Sylla 1996, p. 1)
  8. ^ Buiter, Willem (2009-05-07), Negative interest rates: when are they coming to a central bank near you?, Financial Times, http://blogs.ft.com/maverecon/2009/05/negative-interest-rates-when-are-they-coming-to-a-central-bank-near-you/ 
  9. ^ Ward, Andrew; Oakley, David (2009-08-27), Bankers watch as Sweden goes negative, Financial Times, http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/5d3f0692-9334-11de-b146-00144feabdc0.html 
  10. ^ The Caine Mutiny Part 2, Bill Gross
  11. ^ Financial Repression Redux (Reinhart, Kirkegaard, Sbrancia June 2011)
  12. ^ Norris, Floyd (2010-10-28). "U.S. Bonds That Could Return Less Than Their Price". The New York Times. http://www.nytimes.com/2010/10/29/business/economy/29norris.html. 
  13. ^ a b c Mankiw, N. Gregory (2009-04-18), It May Be Time for the Fed to Go Negative, New York Times, http://www.nytimes.com/2009/04/19/business/economy/19view.html 
  14. ^ a b McCullagh, Declan. "Cash and the 'Carry Tax'". WIRED. http://www.wired.com/politics/law/news/1999/10/32121. Retrieved 2011-12-21. 
  15. ^ See follow-up blog posts for discussion: "Observations on Negative Interest Rates", April 19, 2009; "More on Negative Interest Rates", April 22, 2009; "More on Negative Interest Rates", May 07, 2009, all in Greg Mankiw's Blog: Random Observations for Students of Economics

External links

You can see a list of current interest rates at these sites:

Historical interest rates can be found at: